Japanese
 
Programs
Development and Aid
Green Tax Reform
Climate Change
Earth Summit
Consumption
Water
 
About us
Mission and History
Board Members and Staff
Get Involved
Contact Us
 
JACSES Publications
 
Links
Development and Aid
Green Tax Reform
 
Search
 

Water Privatization

Water Privatisation and
Reform of Irrigation system in Thailand(*1)

Montree Chantawong
Project for Ecological Recovery (PER)

Waterworks
The Metropolitan Waterworks Authority (MWA) and the Provincial Waterworks Authority (PWA) state that enterprises governed under their own law are responsible for waterworks production throughout Thailand. However, as a result of an Asian Development Bank(ADB)-funded study on privatisation of the waterworks authorities in 1995, and loan conditions set by the International Monetary Fund, World Bank and ADB in 1997, the MWA and the PWA are being privitised with the waterworks being sold to the business sector.

The claimed reasons underlying the privatisation of the waterworks are to reduce government spending and to maximise efficiency in providing clean water to the public. At the moment, sources of raw water for waterworks production comes from natural water sources, irrigation systems and groundwater. The government gives priority to the waterworks sector in using (processing and transporting) water.

In privatising the waterworks, the government gives licences to private companies, with concessions being allotted for each of the country's 75 provinces. Under the Waterworks Enterprise Law, a company that receives a licence would become a monopolistic enterprise with a concession to provide waterworks services in a province.

Meanwhile, the government continues to subsidise the privatisation of waterworks. For example, the government sells raw water to the private sector for as low as 0.50 baht (US$0.0119) per cubic metre. And even with this very low price, the companies do not have to bear the costs of construction of irrigation and transportation infrastructure, and are not liable for the social impacts that inevitably emerge as a result of large-scale irrigation development projects.

In the contracts between government and private companies on water purchase, a minimum volume of water to be purchased was guaranteed by the government. If total water-use and purchases are below the volume guaranteed, the government must pay compensation to the companies equal in value to the difference between the volume actually purchased and guaranteed volume. These payments are generally drawn from the taxes paid by Thai citizens. Furthermore, according to these contracts, the government must bear the investment costs on expansions of waterworks infrastructure, despite the fact that it is the licensed companies that are paid for the water delivered to consumers. The costs of expansion will become a part of Thailand's public debt. Moreover, the government has proved its willingness to allow these companies to increase the price of tap water.

All the governmental policies have been undertaken under the marvelous term of "free trade"; but water privatisation in Thailand is creating monopolies and therefore eliminating real competition in the market-place. Under such conditions, the public will not benefit from privatising waterworks either in the short- or long-term.

State Irrigation System
The state's irrigation system includes dams, dikes and canals. Despite being a man-made water system, much of the irrigation system still depends on natural waterways for conveying water to users. The Royal Irrigation Department, the Department for Energy Promotion and Development, and the Electricity Generating Authority of Thailand are major agencies that are responsible for construction and maintenance of the irrigation system.

In recent years, the management of irrigation system has undergone a huge transformation. The perception of the development of the irrigation system has changed from "infrastructure that government must provide for the benefit of farmers" to "investment in irrigation services that guarantee most economic returns". As policy based on this latter perception emerges, the farmers are to pay for water used on their farms and thereby to pay the 'recovery cost' of the irrigation system. With the cost of purchasing water, farmers are driven to grow cash crops that serve the demand of the globalised market, thus reducing their own decision-making power about what food they grow and for whom they grow it. Such changes have resulted from loan conditions(*2) set by the ADB under its Agriculture Sector Program Loan (ASPL) in 1999 and through the technical assistance from the World Bank in preparing the Ninth National Economic and Social Development Plan (2003-2008) in 1999 and 2000. These changes have been formulated under the logic of decreasing governmental spending, maximising efficiency of water usage and promoting free trade.


(*1) This article is excerpted from Chantawong, Montree. Water Privatization in Thailand:Situation and Impact"by."
(*2) In the Development Policy Letter and Policy Matrix, ADB required Thai government to reform water management structure of the country as a condition for the loan. ADB called for a formulation of National Water Resources Policy,an issue of Water Law and an application of policy on cost recovery in irrigation, an increase in National Water Resource Committee
壮 authority in managing water resources nationwide, and an appointment of river basin organizations in three pilot river basins. It also required a privatization of irrigation system by having private company take care of irrigation operation system and having farmers in the irrigated share the cost occurring from water management.

| HOME |

Japan Center for a Sustainable Environment and Society (JACSES)
401, Sanshin Bldg., 2-3-2 Iidabashi, Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo 102-0072 Japan (MAP)
Phone: +81-3-3556-7323 Fax: +81-3-3556-7328 Email:

Copyright JACSES All Rights Reserved.